Chinese economics professor: The making of a moral society

How can one encourage a society where people do things that benefit not just themselves but also others? How can we eliminate bad behaviours and encourage better ones by institutionalising various means of rewarding good behaviour? Chinese economics professor Li Jingkui looks at examples from Chinese modern life and history to find the answers.
This photo taken on 6 September 2021 shows residents looking at a flooded area after heavy rainfalls in Quxian county, Dazhou city, Sichuan province, China. (STR/AFP)
This photo taken on 6 September 2021 shows residents looking at a flooded area after heavy rainfalls in Quxian county, Dazhou city, Sichuan province, China. (STR/AFP)

Recently, there was a major dispute involving a dog and some people.

The incident happened on 2 July at a residential estate in the Chinese city of Bengbu, Anhui province. A self-proclaimed lady boss managing local Huizhou banquets had an altercation with a resident. The former’s off-leash dog almost bit the latter’s daughter, causing much trauma and drama in the process.

Looking at videos circulated online, the dog was not small. In fact, it was medium-sized and rather aggressive. The lady boss could be said to be in the wrong for not putting her dog on a leash. But that was just the beginning. After their scuffle, the lady boss went home while the resident called the police.               

What really gained this lady boss notoriety on the internet was her response when the police stepped in to mediate: “How dare you touch my dog? If you dare lay a finger on it, I will kill your child! Isn’t this all about money? Money is what laozi* has. Laozi organised a few Huizhou banquets and managed them all by myself. Laozi has money and I’m not afraid of you. I can even pay you tens of millions if you wish.”    

In today’s information age, I don’t know if positive events make the news, but negative events certainly spread far and wide with lightning speed. As soon as the video was uploaded, the haughty lady boss instantly became one of the top searches on Weibo.    

Going by the letter of the law

Just a day later on 3 July, the lady boss’s company, Anhui Bengbu Huizhou Banquet Catering Co., Ltd., quickly distanced itself from the woman and subsequently terminated her employment. Soon after, the woman’s husband made an apology.

On the afternoon of 5 July, a branch of the Anhui Bengbu Public Security Bureau posted this statement: “The local public security bureau has administratively detained the two female parties who caused the dispute. The lady boss was detained for seven days, while the girl’s mother — who started the fight first — was detained for three days.” And this was how the incident was resolved. 

A dog rides with people on a front loader through a flooded road following heavy rainfall in Zhengzhou, Henan province, China, 23 July 2021. (Aly Song/Reuters)
A dog rides with people on a front loader through a flooded road following heavy rainfall in Zhengzhou, Henan province, China, 23 July 2021. (Aly Song/Reuters)

In China, the law holds dog owners liable for any harm caused by their off-leash dogs. This is clearly stipulated in the Civil Code of the People's Republic of China (《中华人民共和国民法典》), China’s first civil code and also the first set of laws to be termed a legal code. This code of law was passed on 28 May 2020 and took effect on 1 January 2021.

Article 1245 of this legal code states: “Where a domesticated animal causes damage to another person, the keeper or custodian of the animal shall bear tort liability, provided that his liability may be mitigated or eliminated if it can be proven that the damage is caused by the infringed person intentionally or by gross negligence.”

Going by this, the lady boss has indeed violated relevant regulations by walking her dog off-leash and should be detained. Besides, based on what she said following the incident, we can be certain that her actions were deliberate. A seven-day detention seems very reasonable.  

The lady boss’s behaviour is a classic example of a negative externality in economics. An externality refers to a person’s behaviour bringing harm or benefit to others, without providing the appropriate compensation or reward. Thus, bringing harm to others without giving compensation is a negative externality, while giving benefits to others without gaining a reward is a positive externality.    

By walking her dog off-leash, the lady boss scared the resident’s daughter — this is the harm she brought to the residents of the residential area. But not only did she fail to offer compensation, she did not even apologise for her behaviour — a typical example of a negative externality.

On the other hand, following the examples of comrade Lei Feng (a soldier in the People’s Liberation Army known for his selflessness and devotion to Mao Zedong), or doing good discreetly and without claiming credit is a positive externality. Beautifying one’s garden, or ensuring that one’s desk is neat and tidy at the office may bring cheer to others but one may not be rewarded or compensated for these behaviours. Hence, these are also examples of positive externalities. 

In society, the costs of positive externalities are borne by the actor alone while the benefits are enjoyed by everyone, hence we want more of such behaviour. On the other hand, the benefits of negative externalities are enjoyed by the actor alone while the costs are borne by everyone, so we hate such behaviour.  

Paramilitary police officers patrol Tiananmen Square a day before an event marking the 100th anniversary of the founding of the Communist Party of China, in Beijing, China, on 30 June 2021. (Greg Baker/AFP)
Paramilitary police officers patrol Tiananmen Square a day before an event marking the 100th anniversary of the founding of the Communist Party of China, in Beijing, China, on 30 June 2021. (Greg Baker/AFP)

Most of our laws deal with such externalities. The Criminal Law of the People's Republic of China deals with negative externalities that do greater damage. Additionally, the law also recognises and makes clear the criteria for the recognition of good deeds and courageous acts, and safeguards the rights and interests of good people. By protecting and encouraging positive externalities, good deeds become more meaningful and valuable.     

On the individual level, gossiping is a bad habit that nobody likes. But in a community, such qualities are actually useful for curbing negative externality behaviour and promoting positive externality behaviour within the group. 

Tacitly rewarding good behaviour and punishing bad deeds

However, when an incident escalates to the point that it needs legal recourse, it has often spiralled out of control. In fact, as externalities are everywhere in our daily lives, society has developed various methods to internalise them. Those who commit negative externality behaviours would be made to bear costs that are commensurate with their gains, while those who exhibit positive externality behaviours are offered benefits that "compensate" the costs that they have borne.         

For example, when we praise the owner of a beautiful and tidy garden, it would make him or her feel good about themselves. This is in fact a reward for the owner. We would also avoid colleagues with messy work areas, and would certainly shun someone who does not bathe often and perspires a lot. By exhibiting these social rejection behaviours, we are actually punishing such colleagues to some extent.    

Humans have a natural tendency to judge and gossip about others behind their backs. On the individual level, gossiping is a bad habit that nobody likes. But in a community, such qualities are actually useful for curbing negative externality behaviour and promoting positive externality behaviour within the group.

People walk on a street in Shanghai, China, on 5 August 2021. (Hector Retamal/AFP)
People walk on a street in Shanghai, China, on 5 August 2021. (Hector Retamal/AFP)

Appealing to morals

Scottish economist Adam Smith knew that humans are naturally selfish and self-serving. In his book An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, based on human nature, he argued that an individual’s pursuit of self-interest will bring about unexpected benefits to society.

But in his other work The Theory of Moral Sentiments, he emphasised that humans are endowed with empathy towards others and value the role of an “impartial spectator” within them as the ultimate judge of morality. The example of an incident between Chinese monk Hongyi (Li Shutong) and his good friend Xia Mianzun helps illustrate this.   

Xia and Li were once teachers at the Zhejiang Official Secondary Normal School, where Xia was also the manager of the student dormitories. Once, a student reported a theft at the dormitory and everyone suspected a certain culprit but could not find evidence.

When Xia asked Li for help, the latter said: “Are you willing to commit suicide? You could put up an announcement urging the thief to turn himself in quickly. The notice will also state that If no one comes forward at the end of three days, the dormitory manager will be deemed unfit for his role and will kill himself to uphold the sanctity of education.”

Li was not joking. He said this announcement must be taken seriously — Xia must commit suicide if no one came forward after three days; otherwise, the announcement would be ineffective.

Xia chose to go on a hunger strike instead. Luckily, very soon, the thief came crying and confessed to his misdeed. Such is the power of empathy!

But human nature is pretty complex, as Mencius said in 离娄上 (Li Lou part one) of Mencius (《孟子》): “Virtue alone is not sufficient for the exercise of government; laws alone cannot bring themselves into practice.” It is sometimes difficult to implement order and good governance across a massive society made up of strangers by merely relying on one’s conscience and the “impartial spectator”. But strict laws alone will not work as well, because the cost of implementing the law is too high.     

With the internet, it is even possible that the weight of online public opinion can play a role in social governance if properly used.

Contracts for win-win outcomes

So, are there other ways for humans to solve externality problems? Certainly, and that is by signing contracts to internalise externalities. A famous example of this would be Professor Steven Cheung’s (张五常) research on the contract between beekeepers and farmers.   

People wearing protective masks walk on a street in Shanghai, China, 10 August 2021. (Aly Song/Reuters)
People wearing protective masks walk on a street in Shanghai, China, 10 August 2021. (Aly Song/Reuters)

Assume the following scenario: in a particular region, the farmer is growing a certain number of apple trees and the beekeeper is raising a certain number of bees. Bees collect pollen and nectar and at the same time pollinate the apple trees. In this way, both the farmer and beekeeper have created positive externalities for each other.

However, the farmer and beekeeper are unable to trade, so none of them can receive the benefits of positive externalities. Hence, the government would have to subsidise both the farmer and the beekeeper to encourage such behaviours.        

In the spring of 1972, Professor Cheung spent three months investigating the pricing and contractual agreements of the beekeeping industry in the American state of Washington. Back then, there were about 60 beekeepers in Washington and they each owned 100 colonies or more of bees. In the peak season, the state’s grand total of colonies was about 90,000.

Professor Cheung’s research had a sample size of nine beekeepers and approximately 10,000 spring colonies. He discovered that contractual arrangements have long existed between farmers and beekeepers. In fact, there is a price for the bees' pollen and a nectar-collecting service.  And the accuracy of its price positioning is no less than other market items. 

Such pricing and contractual arrangements proved highly efficient as both farmers and beekeepers got to have a share in the benefits from the bees' work. His study concluded that “the observed pricing and contractual arrangements governing nectar and pollination services are consistent with efficient allocation of resources”.

Human society has used different ways to solve externality problems — appealing to people's morality and conscience as well as their powers of introspection, making use of legal means to enforce law and order, and signing contracts to institutionalise ways for internalising externalities. The right way would vary according to situations, constraints and the value of the transaction. There is no such thing as "one size fits all". With the internet, it is even possible that the weight of online public opinion can play a role in social governance if properly used. This could be one of the constraints of solving today's externality problems in this new era.

*Laozi is a way of referring to oneself in Chinese, meaning "the more senior and superior one talking to you", and is usually used in arguments.

This article was first published in Chinese by Caixin Global as “从徽州宴老板娘遛狗不拴绳说开去”. Caixin Global is one of the most respected sources for macroeconomic, financial and business news and information about China.

Related: Why were Chinese imperial families prone to fratricides and tragedies? | Chinese economics professor: Why we exchange gifts, from ancient China to the present | Chinese economics professor: Fathers are not inferior to mothers when it comes to parenting